Stages of Urban
Development
The conclusion to be drawn from Chapter 2 is
that the urban system is subject to a complicated dynamic process, which, if
left alone, does not lead to a state of equilibrium, but will always be fraught
with friction and produce conflicting reactions from individual population
groups. In what follows an attempt will be made to arrange the many spatial
changes in the urban system along a few main lines.
To that end, use will be made of
an assumed connection between the changes in the structure of the urban system
on the one hand and the development stage of a region or town on the other. We
assume that each stage is characterized by certain specific urban developments,
which tend to be found everywhere unless the government or other actors
consciously try to steer developments in another direction, one country's
experience probably influencing policy in another. It must be noted that this
relationship can vary between countries because the process of accelerated urbanization
started at different points in time.
The definition of the successive
development stages must perforce remain general. It is based on socio-economic
development, its major characteristics being the changes in the structure of
the economy and of income level. As far as economic structure is concerned,
three very broad stages are conceived: first, the transition from a largely
agrarian to an industrial society, second, the transition from an industrial
economy to a tertiary economy, and third, the growth of the tertiary sector to
maturity. In what follows these three stages will be distinguished, and the
spatial changes of a town which can be considered typical of each stage will be
investigated. Very broad definitions are envisaged, which will help to
schematize to some extent the process of urban change.
As has been said earlier, a
description of spatial change must indicate
how the behaviour of the various actors in
the urbanization process
Stages of Urban
Development 25
households, industries, and governments-in
pursuing an increase of wel
fare causes the urban system to evolve. In
this chapter the consequences of the locational behaviour of industries and
households will be the main topic. The part played by the government 'will be
less explicitly dealt with, being kept for discussion in Part III.
3.1. The first stage: urbanization
During the first of the three
stages distinguished, when a country or region can grow no further as an
agricultural economy and gradually becomes an industrial country, the chain of
events is fairly obvious. As a result of population growth and the limited
possibilities of extending available agricultural land, rural districts will
have a growing redundant labour force, entailing a corresponding decrease in
income level. When new industrial employment is created, a migration flow will
be initiated from the country to the towns where it is concentrated. Because in
the early days of the process the income level and the number of hours to be
worked daily do not permit a person to live too far from his work, that flow
will lead to strong urban concentrations and to a decrease in the rural
population. The newcomers are obliged to live in the town itself, in new
residential quarters built around the existing centre, near the factories. This
first phase is characterized, therefore, by the fast expansion of towns with
massive, concentrated town quarters. Similarly, new towns spring up in places
that appear
favourable to industrialization. ,
Such a process of urbanization
was a characteristic development of all the countries of Europe following the
Industrial Revolution in England. In most of them it began in the nineteenth
century, but in some, only after the Second World War. We will come to some
specific differences between these two groups of countries later.
The phenomenon of accelerating
urbanization can manifest itself in different ways. If the country-to-town
movement in a country is oriented largely towards one particular town which
embodies all modern development, that town has a chance of growing into the
national metropolis.
However, the movement may just as well orient
itself to a number of smaller towns scattered across the country. Whether one
or the other
development occurs depends not so much on the
urbanization process itself as on the historical situation in the country
involved, the degree of political centralization or decentralization, and the
propensities of a region, or town within a region, for industrialization. Those
propensities in turn depend on the town's location in the national and
international context, the physical circumstances, the facilities for the
supply of raw materials and the dispatch of final products, and on factors of a
more political nature
26 Urban Europe
such as the policy pursued by the government
with regard to industrialization and providing facilities for the
establishment of industries and the expansion of towns. Together such factors
constitute the conditions and limitations relevant to the locational behaviour
of industries as described earlier. Most urban development at this stage is
linked to existing urban centres, which until then have functioned as
administrative, cultural, religious, commercial, or military centres.
This supports the hypothesis that
an existing urban nucleus, with its attendant agglomeration advantages, is
highly conducive to successful industrialization, and that its diversification
is important for further growth prospects; Yet, in places where the presence of
raw materials, a favourable labour market, or good transport prospects
compensate for the lack of an existing urban milieu, entirely new industrial
towns may come into being.
As far as the spatial structure
of a town is concerned, the most important feature at this stage of the urban
process is the concentration of the development. Towns go through a phase of
concentrated growth amid a stag
nant surrounding territory. If there are
several urban centres near enough to one another, there is a chance of their
growing together to form one agglomeration.
The spatial form of a town is
determined to a great extent by the transport facilities and traffic
provisions available. The stage of economic development and income level force
those who work in the town to go on living there, their choice of residence being
limited by available transport provisions. As transport technologies develop,
the spatial shape of the town evolves. In the early days of the Industrial
Revolution workers had to walk to work, so that houses had of necessity to be
built near to factories. With the advent of railways and tramways longer
distances could be bridged, and towns expanded along the tracks and around the
stations. As public transport in town is the main mode of conveyance, the
townsman's mobility is restricted to the town where he lives, which
consequently is characterized by a high residential density. Within the town
all sorts of public amenities have to be provided for the fast-growing
population, in the fields of medical care, hygiene, education, and recreation.
As a rule, the creation of amenities follows the growth of employment and of
the attracted populationafter a considerable timelag. Without denying that
great social abuse
occurs; we conclude that many people increase
their well-being in this period by moving from country to town. It is not
difficult to appreciate that the highest priority is given to liaving a job and
hence being sure of one's livelihood, however meagre, and that the house and
its surroundings
are considered less important, as also is the
availability of public amenities. It is at the next stage that increase of
welfare will be looked for in the elements that. are still lacking.
Stages of Urban Development 27
Although this pattern is roughly
applicable to both Eastern and Western European countries, it seems worth while
to point out some specific features of developments resulting from time lags in
Eastern European countries as compared to those of Western European nations.
"In the course of the
nineteenth century, Eastern Europe was on the fringe of areas then becoming
urbanized as a result of the industrial revolution." 1 The waves of innovation that originated in
England-the main
growth pole at that time-reached Eastern
Europe late and with consider- .
ably less impetus. This impetus was largely
cushioned by the specific political conditions in the semi-feudal system then
prevailing in Eastern Europe.
A gradual increase in the
division of labour and the developments in technology created conditions for
the emergence of industrial towns. They mainly grew up close to raw-material
resources and in areas that formerly
had well-developed crafts.
The forms of urban settlement continue to
include the following:
-big industrial cities with high spatial
concentration of socio-economic
activities and of population;
-big and medium-sized
conurbations, primarily involved in the extraction of mineral and power-generating
raw materials; this form is also characteristically dense and, in its first
phase, has a relatively poor pattern of links;
-medium-sized and small towns that function
as trading intermediaries
for agriculture.
In each of these forms, the
levels of welfare in the various town quarters inhabited by different
population groups differ considerably. There are no urban transport systems or
other urban systems that service the town over its entire territory. Because of
the lack of adequate transport services, housing developments are located near
town centres and near industrial plants.
Over the period under discussion
the big cities and conurbations undergo changes generated mainly by the
development of urban transport systems, by the extension of water supplies and
sewage systems, the increase in housing construction and the first attempts at
town planning. Town-centres become less densely populated, towns continue to
expand in space, and new industrial centres and housing developments begin to
appear along railway lines for instance. In a few cases, too, new towns are
built according to urban layouts and are provided with the basic system of
technical infrastructure in their centres. The essentially positive changes in
the group of towns under discussion show only one side of the picture; it
I From
S. Herman and J. Regulski, op. cit.
UE1 ~ 0
28 Urban Europe
must also be pointed out that in all of them
slum areas are expanding, as a
result of the immigration of untrained rural
people.
The third of the above~mentioned
forms-the small and the medium~ sized towns-were stagnating, at the expense of
both living conditions and technical infrastructure.
The retarded and relatively weak
impact of the urbanization and indus~ trialization processes in Eastern Europe
produced virtually 110 changes in social or eCOnomic relations in the rural
areas. The big landed estates, applying traditional methods, were a barrier to
progress in agriculture. Accordingly, the already considerable disparity in
welfare between village and town worsened in all aspects, becoming one of the
most essential factors affecting the processes of urbanization over many
decades to come.
Redundant labour in the most
densely populated rural areas was grow~ ing. Onlysotne ofthe jobless could find
work in towns, as the industries there were still underdeveloped. Moreover, the
immigrants lacked the requisite occUpational training. This produced a great
wave of emigration of the East European rural population to the most advanced
West Euro~ pean countries and to the United States.
The nation states that emerged as
new or in a new form as a result of the First World War faced huge problems.
The necessity of integrating their territories according to new boundaries was
the first of these problems. It was often necessary to redesign entire railway
networks. Then individual railway lines were combined in a nationwide network.
In contrast to the railway, the road system was generally of poor quality.
Horses used as draft animals still provided the basic means of transport, as
motoring was still in the fUture.
Some steps were undertaken to
prepare the economic integration of these countries; primarily this involved
the industrialization of what had earlier been fUlly agrarian regions. Hence
the incentive given to the alloca~ tion of new industries outside the existing
industrial centres. Regional power~generating systems were created.
Attempts Were made to reform the
anachronistic agricultural system in order to enCOurage agriculture output and
to help combat rural unemploy~ ment. But the manner in which this was
undertaken was limited in scope and rather ineffectual.
Governments had to intervene in
the towns, where they tried to combat poor housing conditions and the
inevitable building speculation by passing laws protecting occupants on the one
hand and encouraging housing construction on the other. It was at this time
also that the first housing projects on a condominium basis were launched by
various social organiz
ations with a view to creating decent living
conditions for the less-well-off population groups.
Stages of Urban Development 29
The establishment of appropriate
economic bases for the municipal selfgovernments that were il1capable of
coping with the ~ew problems presented another serious difficulty. Through
subsidies, credIt, and conce~sions granted to private enterprises many towns
managed to develop theIr transport system, their communications, and power
supplies. Water and sewage systems and sewage treatment plants, however, did
not meet the towns' real needs. No attempts were made to modernize town
centres. Many towns were in an economic predicament.
In Eastern Europe the end of the
Second World War marked the turning-point. The political system underwent
basic changes, at a ti~e when countries were trying to recover from the damages
of the war and, In some cases, adapting to changes in state boundaries. Top
priority was given to industrial growth.
The industrialization programmes
created a huge demand for manpower in the urbanized areas, and this in turn
caused powerful waves of migration from the rural areas to the towns. The years
of fastest urban growth for the Eastern European countries was between 1960 and
1975.
The migration waves were not
caused by economic considerations alone. The continuing disparity in welfare
level between town and village was another factor. Towns offered access to
education, training, and cultural facilities, w~th all their inherent
advantages. Moreover, farm work, although sorhetimes well paid, enjoyed little
prestige. Gradually emigration to towns resulted in a manpower deficit in
agriculture, although this only really became acute in the next period. Another
factor conducive to the shift of manpower from agriculture was the development
of manufacturing industries, centres of technical services to agriculture, and
basic services in rural areas, all of which provided non~agricultural jobs.
But, as previously mentioned,
capital shortages during the period of reconstruction and the emphasis on the
priority of industrial over other investment naturally reduced expenditures on
social infrastructure, which at that time was still considered non-productive.
This affected urban development in an important way. If urbanization is
measured by the number of people living in towns and by the degree to which
towns are equipped with municipal services, then industrialization can be said
to have outpaced urbanization during this period.
3.2. The second stage: suburbanization
The second stage is referred to
as one of the further developments of the industrial era. Speaking in broad,
schematic terms one might say that urban development, after a period when
factories spring up everywhere
31
there is a fast accelerating evolution in the
economic structure in which
towns grow at the cost of rural areas, has
now ~ntered a stage of con
solidation with its own characteristic
changes In the urban structure.
Although 'towns continue to grow and to
attract people from outside, .the
emphasis at this stage is on qualitative
improvement. In t~rms of the obJective functions of the actors as postulated
in Chapter 2, It could be stated that~with work available and
increasing~priority shifts to better housing and public amenities. These
become available as a result of ~n increase in income, which individually and
collectively is spent accordIng to new
preferences. .
. . .
The evolution of motorized
transport is a decIsive factor In the spatial changes of the town. Extended
public-transport facilities and the int.roductionof buses and private cars
which reach areas not co?nect.ed with .the network of trains and tramways widen
the scope of residential locatIOn. New spacious residential quarters in more
pleasant surroundings, "garden towns" sometimes can now be added to the
city. Town parks and green
belts are designed'; museums,
theatres, schools, and h?spitals are built in
other empty places. In the city
centre itself space IS reserve? ~or new
employment in the tertiary sector, or
existing monumental bUildIngs are given a new function as office buildings.
Factories are moved as much as
possible to the town's periphery where they are less of a nuisance and yet,
thanks to the new modes of trans~o:t, accessible. In the town, banks, offices,
and the whole complex of admmlstrative and personal services inherent in a
complicated, industrial society
are accommodated. It is in this period, too,
that people begin to live out of town while working in the city. The movement
is started by s?:~ll wellto-do groups who, in terms of time, income, and
transport facilities, can afford to move out, and it develops into an inverse
migration flow fast growing in volume. To the people involved, living in a
quiet rural environment is important enough to outweigh the sacrifice of the
mo~e~ and time required for bridging the distance to their work and the
provIsIOns of the town. Given their objective function, they have again
increased their welfare, provided that the infrastructure between their new
residence and t~e
town is adequate. In very nearly all cases it
is the government that IS responsible for that infrastructure, thus the
government has a P?we:ful instrument with which to influence the spatial
pattern of urbamzatlOn. Through the construction of infrastructure and the
provision ~f cert~in forms of transport the government can reinforce or check
certam spatial
tendencies. The better the transport system,
the more a town can expand. .
It seems worth while to point out
at this stage other features that are more or less typical in Eastern European
countries.
In these cOllntries everything
connected with prodllction was given top priority. For this reason, and also
becallse of the lack 'of capital, homing and services were developed at slower
rates.
Programmes for IIrban development
were subordinated to plans for industrial growth. With the exception of the big
cities, expenditure on the construction of new houses was treated as investment
accompanying the construction of new industrial plants. Thlls the small and
medillm-sized towns were left to stagnate. if no industrial plant happened to
be located in them. The small tOwns were particularly affected, as they lost
their function as intermediaries between agricultural production and the
consumer market after centralized integrated systems of agriculture production
and consumption had been created. In contrast to this, regions that formerly
had some industry were developed very rapidly to form urban agglomerations. New
towns emerged, while those in which new industrial establishments were
localized recorded very high rates of growth.
On a parallel with this, ran a
strong tendency to increase the size of industrial establishment and to group
plants in industrial complexes: Thepolicyunderiying this was' an attempt to
lower prime cost through generalized economies of scale. Big complexes of
industry with work forces of up to several thousand people were being
established. The location decision for each. of these industrial groupings had
a powerful' effect on the further course of urbanization and spatial structure
of the country.
Some of the new plants were
localized in less developed regions to ensure their growth. The discovery of
new mineral resources also had a strong effect on location decisions. Very often
such locations were chosen in order to absorb the redundant labour force from
the rural areas around it and to prevent emigration to towns. This again helped
to reduce the demand for new dwellings in the towns.
Most plants, however, were
localized in the existing large industrial centres. One important aspect of
their location was the need for qualified people from rural areas to take jobs
in industry.
In contrast to Western Europe, a
great number of people were able. as a result of transport services. to. go .on
living in their villages and to travel daily to their place of work in the
towns. This kind of commuting increased to such an extent that a special group
of workers-peasants emerged. one in which the head of the family had a job in
the town while the remaining members of the family worked on small farms. The
size of the population group grew in proportion to the implementation of the
industrialization programme. which provided for the location of new industrial
plants in the less advanced regions.
The vast number of commuters
created an immense demand for more extensive mass travel facilities. a sector
which was then given top priority. Urban and suburban transport systems were
developed (tramways, bus lines. electric trains). Business enterprises built
their own independent transport systems for their workers. Private motoring was
still insignificant and. at this stage. not supported by the government.
Travel to work, interindustrial
relationships between complexes of economic activities and the urbanization of
rural areas around the cities and major towns-all these contributed to the
development of the cities into so-called urban agglomerations.
The term urban agglomeration
denotes a group of settlement units whose aggregate population. economic
potentials and functions are distinctly different both in quantity and quality
from the other elements of the nation's settlements system. An agglomeration
consists of the following spatially and functionally integrated elements:
I. A city or a group of towns which form the
central area (the core) of the agglomer
ation.
2. Smaller towns and urban settlements around
the core.
3. Villages whose characteristics have been
transformed to the extent that it seems
justified to designate them as urbanized
areas. .
4. Agrarian areas, forests and recreation
areas which fulfil service functions for the
benefit of the agglomeration's population.
The criteria for delimiting the agglomerations
usually depend on the purpose of the
given study and .on the information available.
ov~r the period under
investigation urban agglomerations grew rapidly in all the
socialist countnes of Europe. This
was the result of the rising rate of economic growth and the co~comltant
dynamic processes of spatial concentration and deconcentration and of spatIal
and functional integration. In a number of cases, commuting played a significant
role to~; this was due to the insufficient housing resources in the central
areas of the agglomeratIons and the concentrated allocation of new industrial
workplaces.
In th~ urban agglomerations, with
big towns or cities at their centres, the biggest
populatIOn and economic potentials
were concentrated. The incipient agglomerations emerglllg l~ areas of newly
discovered raw materials showed the highest growth rates.
The spatIal forrns assumed by urban
agglomerations at this stage were typical of the
premotonng stage: starlike patterns along the
lines of masstransport.2
Generally it can
be said that this phase of suburbanization in Eastern
Europe became established when social
criteria began tQ gain importance.
At this s~ag~
urbanization process involves the development of the social infrastructure
to include. mdlspensable elements in the
equipment of the urban area. Their importance
became widely recOgnized.
Material production and social
infrastructure are mutually interdependent elements in the development
'proce~s. The development of social infrastructure stimulates the development
of ~aten~1 production. Conversely, if the development of infrastructure fails
to
keep pac~ with riSing social need
the development rate of material production may fall, thus addmg to the
.economic and spatial disproportions rather than improving them. An awar~ness
of this s.ltuation led to a gradual increase in the allocation of more capital
for
housmg constructIon and living
space and the raising of minimal living standards. Attempts wer~ made to
introduce new, more attractive and more diversified architectonic
forms to aVOId the monotony of
prefabricated buildings. A full programme aimed at
prOvldlllg the urban population with a range
of services by developing the system of basic
services and sUPPleme:1ting it with better
facilities in town-quarter centres and town
centres began to be put into operation.
At about the sarne time the
working week is being reduced. The extra free time
tOge~~er Wlt~ the rapid
development of private motoring considerably increases spatial
mobility which resulted also in
increased recreation and tourism. Demands for areas
suitable .for weekend recreation
around the towns is rising. Weekend cottages are being
built III Illcreasmg numbers.
The increased eXpenditure for
these purposes made possible a decrease in the disparity
in welfare level between urban and
rural areas. Housing settlements built according to
urban standa:ds Were provided for
the employees of big state-owned farms. The service
systems catenngfor the entire
population, both rural and urban, are being extended.
The social policy carried out in
rural areas must be seen as one element of the overall
policy for the development of
agriculture. Nutrition had become one of the most funda
mental proble~s. T.he rising rate
of consumption tends to exceed the increase in agricul
tUral output, smce In the previous
period less capital was invested in agriculture than in industry. Hence eVery
country has to undertake a comprehensive programme for increasing ItS
agncultural output.
Another result of high industrial
investment was that in towns manpower deficits
become more and more acute. Given
the shortage of labour, increasing employment
no. longer furthers economic
growth. An increase in labour productivity becomes the
pnorlty. . .
Thes~ conditIons lead to the introduction of
programmes for what was called intensive
indust~lal ?eveloPrnent.
Programmes for rapid technological advance are carried out.
AttentIOn IS focuSed therefore on
selected industries in accordance with the desired
distribution of labour. '
2 S. Herman and J. R.cgulski, op. dt.
The modernization of industry
involves the scrapping. of obsolete factories. Small industrial plants
disappear too. Production is. concentrated in separate industrial quarters.
Although this. has' a number of advantages, it does increase commuting distances,
a circumstance women find particularly troublesome. Once this was realized,
small industrial establishments were reintroduced in residential. town
quarters.
The development of a network of
services, the rising rate of housing construction, the specific features of
industrial development, the reshaping of the layout of road networks to suit
the development of motoring~all these factors contribute to the transformation
of the. internal structure of towns.. At the same time, continuing urban.
development reinforces the structure of urban agglomerations and even leads to
the emergence of urbanized regions or districts where several. agglomerations
coalesce. In some cases, such regions extend beyond state boundaries. Their
spatial form also tends to change. Whereas formerly agglomerations developed
generally along main transport lines, at. present the areas between those zones
tend to fill. in, as private motoring increases individual mobility. Thus
agglomerations tend to change in shape from a starlike pattern to that of a
"fat blot" spilling out in all directions.
These big concentrations of
population, industry, and .services n.ecessitate the development of
complicated systems of technical infrastructure. Heating systems for towns and
agglomerations must be constructed as also regional water supplies and sewage
systems. The growing intensification of internal links within agglomerations
leads to the adjustmentof the road network to take the increasing traffic flow
and also to tie in with the development of regional transport systems. The
number of commuter Journeys does not alter, but people travel for a different
reason. Whereas formerly people travelled to work because of the housing
shortage in towns, now they are more likely to travel because they choose to
live away from the centre. More and more people prefer to liVe on the outer
fringes of agglomerations. Town centres become less populated whereas the
suburbs witness rapid, occasionally uncontrolled building activity.
The development and intensification
of primarily industrial production damages the environment in a variety of
ways. Accordingly, plans for the protection of natural amelllties on national,
regional, and agglomeration scale have been worked out. In some areas
industrial development has been reduced, to the benefit of the tourism and
agriculture on which the economic development of those areas depends.
The stage which urban development
has now reached makes it imperative for plans to be coordinated. Hence the
increasing significance of spatial plans. In Eastern Europe as in Western
Europe, long-term plans for the countries' space-economic development and for
comprehensive regional development have been worked out. Those plans are
gaining in importance.
It is necessary to improve upon
previous methods of planning to take into consideration new phenomena and fast
changing circumstances. Correct planning of the development of agglomerations
is especially important.
The stage of development discussed
in this chapter is characteristic of a number ?f cities of relatively recent
vintage, while the socialist countries of Eastern Europe seem stdl to be in the
early phase of this stage.3
The last phase of this stage,
particularly in Western Europe, is notable for the tremendous increase in the
use of the private car and the heavily
increased demand for the elements
of social infrastructure which in due
course come within almost
everybody's reach. The positive and negative
consequences of the introduction
of the private car in urban spatial struc
ture can hardly be overestimated.
The possession of a private car makes it
easier for distances to be
bridged regardless of the location of a public
3 S. Herman and J. Regulski. op. dt.
34
Urban Europe
Stages of Urban Development
35
transport network. Commuter travel is
affected in particular: people no longer need to live near their work or near
public transport services. For large categories of society an entirely new
situation is created; they can now live anywhere within a given wide area and
still have. adequate access to all the elements they consider important to
their welfare. A job in town can easily be combined with living a considerable
distance away, and a number of central provisions in the city will remain
within reach. The tendency that first manifested itself in the building of
garden cities is now being continued on a vast scale.
It is typical of all European
countries where cars are common that many. people aspire to a house of their
own in green surroundings outside the town. The policy of governments and
housing authorities rarely resists that tendency; on the contrary, they
stimulate the outward movement by encouraging large-scale construction outside
towns, hence the massive suburbanization that marks the present spatial changes
in many European towns. The population now grows in the suburbs of central
towns, while in the cities themselves the number of inhabitants is often
decreasing.
Now that towns are spreading over
an ever-increasing area, the terms "urban area" or "urban
district" have become more accurate than "town". Central city
and suburban surroundings are functionally united, and within the larger area
homes and places of work are spatially distributed, as are other places for
recreation, which also have space requirements in the same area.
3.3. The third stage: desurbanization and
inter-urban decentralization
The development described in
Section 3.2 may be called positive in that it meets prevailing needs as regards
housing, recreation, medical care, shopping, etc., and makes for greater living
comfort and has done away with overcrowded town quarters. But there are also
obvious negative consequences, and it must be feared that they will get worse
as the scale of suburbanization becomes larger, the worst problems being those
relating to ~ffi~ .
F or agglomerations which find
themselves in this stage of urban development, existing road infrastructure
can no longer cope with the thousands of commuters w~o on week?ays try to get
into town and find a parking space. The resultmg congestiOn makes all kinds of
workplaces and central provision.s in the city centre less and' less
accessible. Attempts are being made to Improve the centre's accessibility by
improving the infrastructure
and stimulating the use of public
transport. .
To improve the infrastructure, it
is necessary to clear areas for new access roads, to modify the layout of
streets, and to provide extensive parking facilities. The required space is
found mostly in the old residential quarters, which date from the time when
urbanization first started; they are sacrificed in order to modernize and
reconstruct the centre. People living there find themselves compelled to seek
refuge on the outskirts or joining those who have moved to suburban
municipalities.
When the measures to increase the
centre's accessibility by car prove ineffective, there is a good chance that
new service industries will decide to settle in the city centre. Of course,
increased traffic intensity will once more lead to congestion, and to
additional nuisance for the townspeople, thus giving them an additional
stimulus to move to the suburbs. Indeed, it will grow increasingly difficult,
and require ever higher investments, to improve the situation.
Measures that aim at transferring
an increasing proportion of the traffic in city centres from private cars to
public transport have the same indirect result. Improvement of the public
transport services and their extension to the suburban municipalities around
the town does indeed make for easier access to the town by the suburbanites,
but at the same time makes people even more willing to leave the town for the
suburbs. The tendency towards progressive suburbanization and the attendant
continuous need to adapt and extend the infrastructure and the public transport
system at even higher cost will be maintained for as long as tertiary
industries find it worth while to be located in the town centre. As it
functions on an increasingly large scale, the tertiary sector needs more and
more space, which has to be claimed from the older living quarters in the town.
Wherever the process described here occurs, the decline in the number of
inhabitants of the central town may be seen to continue.
In the end, this development
threatens the prosperous existence of the town itself. When the inhabitants
leave town, provisions such as shops, schools, and medical care will soon
follow. If the city centre remains congested there comes a time when offices,
too, are attracted to a location in the suburbs, or even outside the urban district
in other parts of the country, which so far have escaped full urbanization and
remain more accessible because there is no congestion. Not only towns but
suburbs also will decline in population, while elsewhere still rural areas will
be transformed into urban areas, often at the cost of the natural environment
and valuable farmland. This is the stage of desurbanization, attended by interurban
decentralization; we shall discuss it in more detail later on.
In Table 3.1 and in Figs 3.1 and
3.2 the different stages of urban development are shown. During the first
stage the central city (or core) is growing fast, and the suburban (in this
case still rural) ring around the central city
36 |
Urban Europe |
Stages of Urban
Development |
37 |
declines or remains constant in population.
This is the stage of urbanization. In the second stage (suburbanization) the
growth of the central city starts to slacken while gradually the population
of the suburban ring increases. The proportion of the population living in
the ring increases considerably. In the third stage, that of des
urbanization, the point has been reached where the population of the central
city starts declining to such an extent that it results in an absolute
decline of the population of the whole Functional Urban Region (FUR).4 The
spatial development of this stage in the urban life cycle IS very different
from that in the previous stage; no longer is the process characterized by
incremental contiguous or tree-ring-like growth. The absolute decline of the
central city and its suburban commuting hinterland is associated with a
rapid increase in the population and jobs in and around the large (dominant)
FUR within 50-120-kilometre range where the small and medium (subdominant or
satellite) urban areas are to be found. The satellite cities will usually be
at an earlier stage in the urban life cycle than the dominant FUR (Fig. 3.3),
this being reflected, among other things, in their smaller size. The rate of
inter-urban decentralization will be more rapid the greater the regional
dynamism. The
people who are tempted to migrate to the small and medium-sized cities may
well be returning from a suburban to an urban life-style, albeit in a
smaller-sized urban centre. Such a move may reflect a wish to avail
themselves of several benefits: better access to work, improved service |
4 For definition of Functional Urban
Regions, see Chapter 5. |
Stages of Urban Development |
39 |
provision and more open space, often more
living space, access to the countryside and a wide range of
recreational opportunities. and the wish to avoid the numerous economic and
social costs incurred in the original location. |
The
decentralization of the population and latterly of jobs is a process that
characterizes urban systems in the desurbanization stage, irrespective of
their size, .region, or location in relation to other cities; what varies is
the rate at which this process operates (Fig. 3.4). Cities in the
prosperous regions
of a country are apt to decentralize more rapidly than those in the peripheral
or less prosperous regions. The size of the city system is also important
in explaining rates of decentralization, mostly because size is related
to the density of the urban core, which is linked in turn to the stage that
a city has reached in its life cycle. The process is also determined by the
role that a FUR performs in the national settlement system. |
Urban Europe |
Stages
of Urban Development 41 arises
as to what evolutionary stage we may expect next. We shall try to identify
and systematize these stages. Let us start with the simple definition
that the total area of urban land in use for urban purposes in a FUR equals
the product of the number of households (population divided by the average
growth of a household) and the average land-use per household. So: p A = s pJ) f |
40 3.3.1.
The national settlement system The
development of inter-urban decentralization of large FURs in the
desurbanization stage and the rapid expansion of medium-sized towns is ne
aspect of city-system interdependency in advanced economies. Indi °idual
FURs no longer grow and change in isolation but are greatly ~nfluenced
by events taking place elsewhere in the national settlement sys tem.
The interdependencies are affected by flows of goods, services, information,
decisions and capital between various sectors of the economy. As most
employment is concentrated in urban areas, the pattern and intensity f
such flows will inevitably determine the processes of urban development. o The
properties of city-systems have traditionally been described in terms f
rank-size distributions, central place theory, growth pole theory, hierar o
hical diffusion, and the like. It is questionable whether such inductive ~ules
and theories are at all useful in explaining the contemporary spatial organization
of settlements. An understanding of these processes wi!! ultimately depend
on improving knowledge on the perception, evaluation, and decision-making of
major actors who in turn are largely influenced by the structural components
of the social means of production. |
in which |
A
= total area of urban land, P total
population, f
= average household size, s = area per household. We may also write (3J) as: A = P + .~ -.i: (3.2) The
point over the symbols indicates that we are dealing with relative changes oVer a period of time. . . . Now we do know one or two things about the quantities contaIned In
the right-hand side of equation (3.2). The total population of a FUR has been
mentioned more than once in previous pages, and we know that there comes a
point where the population of large FURS falls into a decline, and P, thus,
becomes negative. .~ is the relative growth of area per household. We assume that it
will remain positive, but decreasingly so. In other words, we assume that the
demand for land per household will grow further (land for provisions and job
opportunities included), but to a decreasing extent. . j, lastly,
representing the relative growth of the average household, IS negative. The
average household is becoming even smaller. The scope for reduction being,
naturally, limited-a household can hardly consist of less than one person-the
relative decrease will tend asymptotically towards zero. The
four factors have been combined and are shown in Fig. 3.5. During the first
period (0 - tA) the population, the number of house-. holds,
and the total demand for land all increase. Desurbanization, though heralded
by the evolution through time of the various quantities, has not yet set in. tA is' the crucial point in time where the first stage of desurbanization (fA tB) begins, the stage at
which the population falls but the number of households as well as the total
demand for land for urban . purposes goes on rising. At tB the loss in population exceeds
t~e consequences of decreasing family size; the number of households begIns
to fall |
3.4.
The future: reurbanization? The process of accelerated desurbanization and deconcentration described
above depicts one alternative future. Another is that of reurbanization
(Fig. 3.1). In Western Europe, both local and central governments have woken
up to the possibility of turning the tide in their large cities and restoring
their image, by rehabilitating the existing housing stock, introducing
urban-renewal programmes, improving the traffic situation, creating pedestrian zones, and upgrading the social in,frastruct.ure. Whether
su.ch measures will persuade more people to stay In the CIty and also
entIce people from outside the city to come and settle is hard to say. The
trend towards the desurbanization in the largest cities seems too general and
so trong
that only through the application of a most rigorous policy could :ignificant
results be expecte~, and such a po!icy has yet to be d~~eloped. .It seems
inevitable, then, that In the not too dIstant future our cItIes, and In articular
the large FURS, will be facing a host of problems. The rather ~essimistic
considerations contained in subsection 3.4.1 may be helpful in explaining
what these problems are. |
3.4.1. Stages of desurbanization It was concluded in Section 3.4 that the
developments taking place in the large FURS of Western Europe are likely to continue, and the question |
42 |
Urban Europe |
Stages of Urban Development |
43 |
in the absolute sense. It is the second
stage of desurbanization, in which the phenomena of decline are becoming more
manifest. The last point of interest is fe, beyond which neither the
greater demand for land per household nor the smaller average size of
households can compensate any longer for the loss of population, so that the
absolute demand for urban land is diminishing, too. Beyond point fe the
town faces the necessity of contracting in the absolute physical sense. |
3.4.2.
The consequences of desurbanization To
find out what the consequences of desurbanization are, let us look at each
stage somewhat closer. It will soon appear that the consequences are
cumulative, that is to say, new results add themselves to and reinforce
earlier ones. The whole process has a snowball effect and threatens to lead
eventually to a town's total downfall, turning a living entity into a ghost
town. The first stage is marked by continuing
physical expansion of the town (land area, houses) and simultaneous
contraction of the population. Though there are no exact figures available,
from the little evidence there is it may ~e inferred that the change in the
net migration-a major cause of populatIon loss-can be imputed partly to the
increased exodus of the h~gher income groups and partly to the dwindling
desire among the same ~md of people to mI~r.ate from rural areas to a big
city. Even if the average mcome of the remammg group of city dwellers
continues to rise the in crease in the number of well-to-do
inhabitants may well entail a' cutback in the total income of the urban
population. And what that means is obvious: less turnover for retailers, for
the catering trade, and for other service~. Public transport, already facing
fast-growing deficits, sees its market dwmdle, while the municipality finds
its budget has shrunk and its social services are financially undermined. It
is quite likely that housebuilding will stagnate as soon as the second stage
is felt to be imminent. By the end of the first stage there will be no net
demand for new houses; after it, there will be a surplus. This would not be
so bad in a period of fast rising incomes, when houses tend to become
obsolete q~ickl'y because of the dwindling demand for cheap houses; in such a
penod It would be feasible to build new houses and discard the cheaper and
older ones. But in a state of desurbanization one cannot count on f~st income
growth, any more than on the need to replace the existing ?ousmg stock at a
high rate with new ones more in line with higher mcomes. The less so, when
there is an increasing tendency to renovate existing houses instead of
simultaneously demolishing old and constructing new houses. What is certain is that the more the demand
still existing for new houses is met at this stage, the greater will be the
surplus in the next stage. That is wh~ it is hi~hly opportune to investigate
carefully during the first stageWhICh a senes of towns have already
entered-the extent to which we are justified
in meeting the demand for housing in view of the absolute decline in total
demand for houses that can be envisaged in the foreseeable future. The
second stage, as has been said before, is marked by a shrinking population, a
decrease in the number of households (hence less demand for |
One
wonders what the consequences of such an evolution may be. Some people may
believe that the processes of expansion and contraction are bound JO occur
side by side and will continue to do so. So, if the urban population at a
given moment shows a marked predilection for smaller agglomerations and
medium-sized towns, that is-according to these people-a natural phenomenon,
not to be considered unusual, and to be accepted with all its consequences. Now,
to form an opinion on this matter we need to look at the phenomena a little
closer and to evaluate them. In this way we can decide whether it is
preferable to let the process run its course, check it, or try to reverse it. |
UE1 _ E |
44 Urban
Europe
houses), but a continuing increase in the use
of urban land. A drop in the demand for houses causes great difficulties in the
construction trade, the more so because incomes can hardly be expected to rise
in the period involved (see above). In fact, it is now the turn of employment
in the building sector, alongside that in the service sectors, to plummet. In stage
2 more houses will be demolished than built, the cleared sites being used for
other purposes, for the total demand for land is still increasing at this
stage.
Awkward questions will now
present themselves. If houses have to be demolished at all, which shall we
condemn, those recently renovated, or the newer ones of lower quality? Where
shall we start demolishing, in the central town or in the ring? Is it likely,
or not, that more land will be required exactly where the housing stock is
becoming smaller? Such questions are difficult and far from encouraging. The
picture is becoming grim.
The climax, or rather the nadir,
of the transformation is reached in the third and last stage, in which to the
former disintegrating processes is added the phenomenon of cleared sites being
left unused. In this period there is neither reason nor money left to give
those sites a meaningful purpose. The most logical solution is perhaps to raze
the worst quarters to the ground and to turn them into green belts, so that
eventually there will be a green-bordered town core surrounded by an urbanized,
but shrinking ring of built-up areas. It seems logical, but would it be wise?
Much capital is being invested in the renovation of precisely those old
quarters, capital that is bound to depreciate faster than its investors
envisage.
The alternative, starting the
demolition programme in the ring, is not attractive either. By so doing, too
much capital would be sacrificed to adapt the town to the diminishing number of
households. Advantage would be gained from clearing bits of land which could
for the greater part be restored to its original agrarian function (it would be
better not to dwell on the cost price of those bits of land, however).
Wherever one starts the town is
going to fall to pieces, showing gaps where land lies fallow. There will be a
general decline which cannot fail to affect social relationships, crime, and
cultural decay. Cultural and social bloom in the midst of absolute economic
downfall is not a regular feature of our society.
The prospects are no less than frightening.
All the more so if the process of economic decline has to be paid for with vast
loss of capital in all sectors of economic life. Large-scale urban decline, in
the sense of an overall deterioration of urban functions, could have serious
consequences for society in the countries afflicted, for it heralds the
complete ruin of the urban culture of the twentieth century. If such a
disastrous state of affairs is to be warded off, reurbanization must be brought
about fast and resolutely. Traffic problems dominate the present urban scene,
and to resist urban
Stages of Urban Development 45
decline it will be necessary first of all to
solve them. Experience has taught that the desired effect can be expected only
from measures that manage to reduce traffic demand. Such measures must restrain
suburbanization, and accomplish the reurbanization of central towns by giving
new support to their residential function. To that end, industries will have to
be redistributed across the whole urban area in such a way that home-to-work
distances are reduced and the use of the existing infrastructure made less
one-way than it is now. Positive measures to achieve these ends have already
been introduced in several European countries.
It has been assumed that shifts
in the economic structure, the level of well-being, and the government's policy
underlie the described spatial changes in urbanization. The changes involved
are seen primarily as the results of actions by individuals and industries,
motivated by their aspirations to a higher welfare level. The government's
role in the process has
been discussed far less explicitly. Yet, as
representative of the general inter-.
est the government has a very specific task.
When the urbanization process is perceived to lead to discrepancies and
unacceptable loss of well-being for certain groups of the population-the
result, at least partially, of past government action-it is for the government
to regulate and adjust matters in such a way as to ensure more welfare for
everybody. In the section dealing with urban actors attention has already been
given to the role of the government in general and to its objectives and powers
of action.
In Part III the theory of
urban policy and its instruments will be treated more specifically. Actual urban
policy, within the context of regional policy, will also be treated after the
empirical analysis of urban development trends in Part II.